首页
外语
计算机
考研
公务员
职业资格
财经
工程
司法
医学
专升本
自考
实用职业技能
登录
外语
Rich North, Hungry South A few years ago, the rich world’s worry about economic interaction with developing countries was th
Rich North, Hungry South A few years ago, the rich world’s worry about economic interaction with developing countries was th
admin
2010-04-30
52
问题
Rich North, Hungry South
A few years ago, the rich world’s worry about economic interaction with developing countries was that the poor could not profit from it. So unbalanced were terms of exchange between the North’s mighty industries and the South’s weakling sweatshops that trade between the two could be nothing more than exploitation of the one by the other: far from helping the poor countries, global integration would actually deepen their poverty. This fear has now given way to a pessimism that is equal and opposite—namely, that trade with the developing world will impoverish today’s rich countries.
Like the previous scare, this view contains an iota of truth—enough to lend plausibility. Also like its processor, it is a hysterical exaggeration. However, this new fear is more dangerous than the old one. The earlier scare tacitly affirmed that the industrial countries would suffer if they cut their links with the third world. Starting from there, campaigning in the North to restrict trade with developing countries was going to be an uphill straggle. Those who oppose deeper economic integration now have a better platform. Vital interests oblige the rich countries to protect their industries from the new onslaught. Unlike its processor, this idea may sell.
The grip that this thinking already has on popular opinion owes little to economic history or principles. The new fear, like the old one, express the conviction that growth in one part of the world must somehow come at the expense of another. This is a deeply rooted prejudice, and plainly wrong. Very nearly all of the world is more prosperous now than it was 30 years ago. Growth has been a story of mutual advance, not redistribution; and where living standards have not improved in recent decades (notably, in parts of Africa), excessive integration in the international economy has not been the cause.
Lending useful support to this first error is a second—the idea that there is only so much work to go round. If new technologies render some jobs obsolete, or if an increase in the supply of cheap imports makes other jobs uneconomic, the result must be a permanent rise in unemployment. Again, on a moment’s reflection, this is wrong: otherwise, technological progress this century would have pushed unemployment rates in the industrial countries to something in excess of 95%.
At the core of both fallacies is blindness to the adaptive power of a market economy. When today’s rich economies were predominantly agricultural, it seemed certain that rapidly rising farm productivity (thanks to new technology) would create a permanent army of unemployed. In the days of labor-intensive manufacturing, the same fears were expressed about labor-saving technology in the factory. Farm employment in the industrial countries has dwindled to nearly nothing: manufacturing employment in America now stands at a mere 15% of the labor-force. But other jobs have taken their place. As a result, these changes have happened alongside—indeed, they have been part and parcel of—an extraordinarily rapid, persistent and widely shared improvement in living standards.
Yet it does not suffice to refute elementary fallacies. Sophisticated alarmists avoid them (taking care, obviously, not to educate their listeners). But carefully, their case goes as follows. The breadth and intensity of third-world competition is increasing. The pressure is concentrated on particular parts of the economy—for the moment, on low-skill manufacturing. Wages there are being forced down and jobs lost. This change will accelerate. Modem societies (with weak ties of family and religion) are no longer equipped to withstand such strains. The result will be great social distress.
This argument rests on a series of claims that need to be examined one by one. One survey does this at length. It agrees that in many industries the developing countries are offering much stiffer competition than before, and that this will continue. It also agrees that the wages and jobs of low-skilled workers are under pressure as a result. But it argues, first, that these effects have been overdone. Third-world incomes are automatically regulated by international differences in productivity; the faster their advantage in cheap labor will be eroded. Moreover, that advantage has itself been exaggerated. Labor costs are only a small part of total costs, especially in manufacturing; in other respects—in complementary physical and human capital—the poor countries will remain at a big disadvantage for years.
So the pressures have been overstated. On the other hand, what the industrial countries stand to gain from faster growth in the third world has been altogether ignored. Stronger competition will push rich-country producers to invest more and improve their efficiency; expanding markets for rich-country exports will allow them to reap new economies of scale. Even more important is the direct effect that greater productivity in the third world will have on the North’s standard of living. Cheaper imports mean lower prices and, hence, higher real incomes. The potential gain is large.
In the aggregate, the economic benefits to the North from faster growth in the third world seem certain to outweigh the costs. Remember the gains to the world’s poor countries and the global benefits are immense. And yet, you might ask, What consolation is this to the rich countries’ losers? Perhaps the social costs for the North are so great that the economic gain should be refused.
Suppose this is right, it would follow that new technology ought to be resisted with even greater urgency than imports from the third world. Technological progress, after all, is an even more powerful engine of economic change. It asks the citizens of rich countries to strike the same bargain they are offered by faster growth in the developing world: in the aggregate, it benefits them, but there are losers along the way. Ross Perot and the other leading alarmists on third world growth have not yet argued for prohibitive taxes on all forms of labor-saving innovation. This can only be an oversight. Innovation remains the greater threat social harmony—and believing this requires no imagination. Machines have been destroying jobs, wrecking communities and spreading misery for centuries.
Doubtless, some argue seriously for a punitive innovation tax. Most people would regard the idea as absurd. Why? Not because new technology brings nothing but good (the social costs are real) but
because, with time, the benefits overwhelm the costs. So it will prove with trade with the developing world.
As in accommodating the changes brought by new technology, however, governments have an important job—to protect the losers without denying the benefits to citizens at large. This is a crucial point: if the case against trade with the third world gains ground, it will be partly because governments fail in that challenge. It will not do to provide a welfare system that pays a subsistence income to those whose jobs disappear, for boredom and idleness, even at a bearable standard of living, are socially corrosive. Far more needs to be done to help workers acquire the skills they need to switch jobs—and, in many cases, to equip them with the literacy and numeracy that they may well have lacked in the first place. Steadily expanding programs of adults’ education, better job-placement services, grants and other help for those who need to move house to find work, and explicit subsidies for some kinds of low-wage employment would all be sensible ways to spend part of the dividend that growth in the South will pay to the North.
This is an agenda that governments have been too slow to develop. Unless they start to act soon, the alarmists may win more converts. And the marvelous opportunity that is now before the world may be jeopardized. To build obstacles on the developing countries’ path out of poverty would be the crime of the century. Happily, it is preventable.
The passage manly refutes the wrong ideas about the economic interaction between rich and poor countries.
选项
A、Y
B、N
C、NG
答案
A
解析
本题的关键词是the wrong ideas about the economic interaction,寻读时,文章首段就已说明两种错的观点,随后行文中针对它们展开了具体的阐述,故为Y。
转载请注明原文地址:https://kaotiyun.com/show/3AOK777K
0
大学英语六级
相关试题推荐
A、Learnmoregrammarandvocabulary.B、WatchmoreBBCtelevisionprograms.C、UnderstandSpanishcultureswell.D、Domorepractic
A、Hehasdecidedhowhe’sgoingtospendtheprizemoney.B、Hedoesn’tknowhowmuchhisrentisgoingtoincrease.C、He’salrea
A、Itcancausefloodingannually.B、Itcancarrydiseasesthataffectanimals.C、Itcanintroducetoomuchsaltintothesoil.D
Mr.PamelaLundquist,anexpertonhealth,gaveus____________________(如何用自然的方法让室内空气变得新鲜的一点建议).
Fatherhoodisgoingtohaveadifferentmeaningandbringforthadifferentresponsefromeverymanwhohearsthesewords.Some
A、Agriculturalproducts.B、Manufacturedfoods.C、Settlers.D、Farmanimals.AWhatwasusuallytransportedfromwesttoeast?
GriffithworkedforafirmthatspecializedineconomicdevelopmentinWashingtonD.C.becausesheneededmoneytopayforherd
GriffithworkedforafirmthatspecializedineconomicdevelopmentinWashingtonD.C.becausesheneededmoneytopayforherd
FreedbySudan,"Geographic"ReporterArrivesHomeinU.S.After34daysinaSudanesejail,NationalGeographicjournalist
A、Venusistoohot.B、Thereisnowaterthere.C、Thereisnooil.D、Itislackingincarbondioxide.A该题问“根据卡尔教授的说法,金星的大气存在什么问题?
随机试题
精囊睾丸
A.合欢皮B.酸枣仁C.远志D.琥珀E.磁石既能活血散瘀,又能镇惊安神的药物是()
下列关于派许加权指数的计算中,错误的是()。
下列各项中,不符合消费税有关规定的是( )。
甲、乙、丙三位自然人出资设立A有限责任公司,公司初步拟定的章程部分内容为:公司注册资本8万元;公司不设股东会、董事会和监事会,甲为公司执行董事兼公司监事,乙为总经理。公司成立后,发生以下事项:(1)A公司拟作为唯一股东出资9万元设立B一人有限责任公司,专
2013年10月23日—24日,由科技部信息中心主办,上海市科技信息中心承办的部分省市科技信息服务部门电子政务工作研讨会在上海召开。科技部信息中心主任胡晓军、上海市科委巡视员徐美华出席了会议。会议围绕贯彻落实党的十八大精神,进一步推动全国科技信息
如果新产品打开了销路,则本企业今年就能实现转亏为盈。只有引进新的生产线或者对现有设备实行有效的改造,新产品才能打开销路。本企业今年没能实现转亏为盈。如果上述断定是真的,则以下哪项也一定是真的?I.新产品没能打开销路。Ⅱ.没引进新的生产线。Ⅲ.对现有设
已知线性方程组(Ⅰ)线性方程组(Ⅱ)的基础解系ξ1=[-3,7,2,0]T,ξ2=[-1,-2,0,1]T.求方程组(Ⅰ)和(Ⅱ)的公共解.
Mr.Browntoldhissonthat______.Whatwasburnt?
Thereisvirtuallynolimittohowonecanservecommunityinterests,fromspendingafewhoursaweekwithsomecharitableorga
最新回复
(
0
)