首页
外语
计算机
考研
公务员
职业资格
财经
工程
司法
医学
专升本
自考
实用职业技能
登录
外语
Rich North, Hungry South A few years ago, the rich world’s worry about economic interaction with developing countries was th
Rich North, Hungry South A few years ago, the rich world’s worry about economic interaction with developing countries was th
admin
2010-04-30
78
问题
Rich North, Hungry South
A few years ago, the rich world’s worry about economic interaction with developing countries was that the poor could not profit from it. So unbalanced were terms of exchange between the North’s mighty industries and the South’s weakling sweatshops that trade between the two could be nothing more than exploitation of the one by the other: far from helping the poor countries, global integration would actually deepen their poverty. This fear has now given way to a pessimism that is equal and opposite—namely, that trade with the developing world will impoverish today’s rich countries.
Like the previous scare, this view contains an iota of truth—enough to lend plausibility. Also like its processor, it is a hysterical exaggeration. However, this new fear is more dangerous than the old one. The earlier scare tacitly affirmed that the industrial countries would suffer if they cut their links with the third world. Starting from there, campaigning in the North to restrict trade with developing countries was going to be an uphill straggle. Those who oppose deeper economic integration now have a better platform. Vital interests oblige the rich countries to protect their industries from the new onslaught. Unlike its processor, this idea may sell.
The grip that this thinking already has on popular opinion owes little to economic history or principles. The new fear, like the old one, express the conviction that growth in one part of the world must somehow come at the expense of another. This is a deeply rooted prejudice, and plainly wrong. Very nearly all of the world is more prosperous now than it was 30 years ago. Growth has been a story of mutual advance, not redistribution; and where living standards have not improved in recent decades (notably, in parts of Africa), excessive integration in the international economy has not been the cause.
Lending useful support to this first error is a second—the idea that there is only so much work to go round. If new technologies render some jobs obsolete, or if an increase in the supply of cheap imports makes other jobs uneconomic, the result must be a permanent rise in unemployment. Again, on a moment’s reflection, this is wrong: otherwise, technological progress this century would have pushed unemployment rates in the industrial countries to something in excess of 95%.
At the core of both fallacies is blindness to the adaptive power of a market economy. When today’s rich economies were predominantly agricultural, it seemed certain that rapidly rising farm productivity (thanks to new technology) would create a permanent army of unemployed. In the days of labor-intensive manufacturing, the same fears were expressed about labor-saving technology in the factory. Farm employment in the industrial countries has dwindled to nearly nothing: manufacturing employment in America now stands at a mere 15% of the labor-force. But other jobs have taken their place. As a result, these changes have happened alongside—indeed, they have been part and parcel of—an extraordinarily rapid, persistent and widely shared improvement in living standards.
Yet it does not suffice to refute elementary fallacies. Sophisticated alarmists avoid them (taking care, obviously, not to educate their listeners). But carefully, their case goes as follows. The breadth and intensity of third-world competition is increasing. The pressure is concentrated on particular parts of the economy—for the moment, on low-skill manufacturing. Wages there are being forced down and jobs lost. This change will accelerate. Modem societies (with weak ties of family and religion) are no longer equipped to withstand such strains. The result will be great social distress.
This argument rests on a series of claims that need to be examined one by one. One survey does this at length. It agrees that in many industries the developing countries are offering much stiffer competition than before, and that this will continue. It also agrees that the wages and jobs of low-skilled workers are under pressure as a result. But it argues, first, that these effects have been overdone. Third-world incomes are automatically regulated by international differences in productivity; the faster their advantage in cheap labor will be eroded. Moreover, that advantage has itself been exaggerated. Labor costs are only a small part of total costs, especially in manufacturing; in other respects—in complementary physical and human capital—the poor countries will remain at a big disadvantage for years.
So the pressures have been overstated. On the other hand, what the industrial countries stand to gain from faster growth in the third world has been altogether ignored. Stronger competition will push rich-country producers to invest more and improve their efficiency; expanding markets for rich-country exports will allow them to reap new economies of scale. Even more important is the direct effect that greater productivity in the third world will have on the North’s standard of living. Cheaper imports mean lower prices and, hence, higher real incomes. The potential gain is large.
In the aggregate, the economic benefits to the North from faster growth in the third world seem certain to outweigh the costs. Remember the gains to the world’s poor countries and the global benefits are immense. And yet, you might ask, What consolation is this to the rich countries’ losers? Perhaps the social costs for the North are so great that the economic gain should be refused.
Suppose this is right, it would follow that new technology ought to be resisted with even greater urgency than imports from the third world. Technological progress, after all, is an even more powerful engine of economic change. It asks the citizens of rich countries to strike the same bargain they are offered by faster growth in the developing world: in the aggregate, it benefits them, but there are losers along the way. Ross Perot and the other leading alarmists on third world growth have not yet argued for prohibitive taxes on all forms of labor-saving innovation. This can only be an oversight. Innovation remains the greater threat social harmony—and believing this requires no imagination. Machines have been destroying jobs, wrecking communities and spreading misery for centuries.
Doubtless, some argue seriously for a punitive innovation tax. Most people would regard the idea as absurd. Why? Not because new technology brings nothing but good (the social costs are real) but
because, with time, the benefits overwhelm the costs. So it will prove with trade with the developing world.
As in accommodating the changes brought by new technology, however, governments have an important job—to protect the losers without denying the benefits to citizens at large. This is a crucial point: if the case against trade with the third world gains ground, it will be partly because governments fail in that challenge. It will not do to provide a welfare system that pays a subsistence income to those whose jobs disappear, for boredom and idleness, even at a bearable standard of living, are socially corrosive. Far more needs to be done to help workers acquire the skills they need to switch jobs—and, in many cases, to equip them with the literacy and numeracy that they may well have lacked in the first place. Steadily expanding programs of adults’ education, better job-placement services, grants and other help for those who need to move house to find work, and explicit subsidies for some kinds of low-wage employment would all be sensible ways to spend part of the dividend that growth in the South will pay to the North.
This is an agenda that governments have been too slow to develop. Unless they start to act soon, the alarmists may win more converts. And the marvelous opportunity that is now before the world may be jeopardized. To build obstacles on the developing countries’ path out of poverty would be the crime of the century. Happily, it is preventable.
The economic benefits to the North from faster growth in the third world ______the costs.
选项
答案
seem certain to outweigh / outweigh / overwhelm
解析
本题的关键词是“The economic benefits”和“costs”,寻读到倒数第5段就可确定二者间的关系,所以 seem certain to outweigh/outweigh/overwhelm都可与之符合。
转载请注明原文地址:https://kaotiyun.com/show/DAOK777K
0
大学英语六级
相关试题推荐
Thinktwicenexttimesomeoneasksyoufor"fiveminutesofyourtime"itcouldcostyoumorethanyouthink.ABritishprofesso
A、Thechildrenaretooyoungtobenefitfromcitylife.B、Evenadultsthemselvescannotgoeverywhereinthecity.C、Thereisa
A、Heshouldlistenmoretotheteacher.B、Heshouldtakepartinsomesocialactivities.C、Heshouldmakeanappointmentwithhi
Ice-cream’soriginsareknowntoreachbackasfarasAlexandertheGreat,althoughnospecificdateorpersonalityhavebeencr
A、Apen.B、Aschoolbag.C、Abook.D、Apencil.AWhatfreegillscanchildrengetfromthelibrarythisyear?
A、Hethinksitisapitythatthereisaflawonit.B、Hethinksitisagoodbargainbutitcouldbemuchcheaper.C、Hethinks
Theemployeragreedto______(就提高工人工资向工人做出让步).
EvaluationbyStudents1.不少大学让学生参与任课老师教学情况的测评2.对此改革措施校方、教师、学生的看法不一3.学生测评教师的益处以及可能产生的问题
FreedbySudan,"Geographic"ReporterArrivesHomeinU.S.After34daysinaSudanesejail,NationalGeographicjournalist
Iwasadvisedtobecautious___________________(以防他对我的工作不良企图).
随机试题
阅读下面一段课文,回答下列问题:和戎诏下十五年,将军不战空临边。朱门沉沉按歌舞,厩马肥死弓断弦。戍楼刁斗催落月,三十从军今白发。笛里谁知壮士心?沙头空照征人骨。中原干戈古亦闻,岂有逆胡传子孙。遗民忍死望恢复,几处今宵垂泪痕!这首诗具有什么样的
慢性充血性心力衰竭,以下哪项治疗措施可改善其远期预后
A、PVAB、PEGC、CAPD、HPMCE、EudragitE100常用作片剂黏合剂的是
建筑师每年参加继续教育的时间累计不得少于()[2011年第71题]
当合同履行过程中发现,对给付货币的地点,合同中没有明确约定,事后双方又未能达成补充协议,根据《合同法》,应在()履行。
下列关于质量事故书面报告的内容说法正确的是()。
下列各项中,应纳入应付职工薪酬核算的有()。
一般纳税企业,下列经济业务所涉及的增值税,应作为销项税额处理的是()。
教育学是一门研究教育的科学,它属于社会科学的范畴。()
皮亚杰把人的认识发展划分为不同的阶段,下列属于形式运算阶段的心理特点的有()。
最新回复
(
0
)