首页
外语
计算机
考研
公务员
职业资格
财经
工程
司法
医学
专升本
自考
实用职业技能
登录
外语
Laos, a poor country of 6 million people wedged between Vietnam and Thailand, has no openings to the sea and few routes to world
Laos, a poor country of 6 million people wedged between Vietnam and Thailand, has no openings to the sea and few routes to world
admin
2017-04-20
83
问题
Laos, a poor country of 6 million people wedged between Vietnam and Thailand, has no openings to the sea and few routes to world attention. But it is now enjoying a rare moment in the sun. Last month it won approval to join the World Trade Organisation. This week it hosted the ninth Asia-Europe meeting, which brings together leaders from the world’s most and least dynamic regions. Its small economy, which exports gold, copper and hydropower, is distinguishing itself. Its growth rate is not only one of the fastest in the world but also one of the steadiest.
In spite of the fluctuated growth rate worldwide, growth in developing Asia, especially in Indonesia and Bangladesh, is now steadier, as well as faster, than growth in the "mature" economies of the G7. The "Great Moderation" is the name given to the era of economic tranquility that prevailed in America and elsewhere in the rich world before the financial crisis. Should the label now be applied to Asia?
Asia’s economies are better known for their speed than their stability. Even now some highly open economies, such as Thailand, Singapore, remain more volatile than the global average. Exposed to international trade flows, their industrial output fluctuates like a twirling ribbon with every twitch of demand.
But developing Asia (which excludes rich economies like Singapore, South Korea) is dominated by populous countries that rely increasingly on domestic demand to drive their economies. Household consumption contributed half of the growth of just over 6% Indonesia enjoyed in the year to the third quarter. Developing Asia’s combined current-account surplus, which reflects its dependence on foreign demand, more than halved from 2008 to 2011 and is expected to fall further this year.
Asia’s stability also owes something to demand management. During the Asian financial crisis, policymakers faced a dilemma. They could defend their exchange rates by raising interest rates. But that would cripple borrowers. Or they could let their currencies fall and ease rates. But that would inflate the burden of foreign-currency debt, crippling borrowers too.
In the aftermath of the crisis the region worked its way out of this trap. Most countries accumulated an impressive stock of hard-currency reserves and weaned themselves off foreign-bank loans in favour of foreign equity and local-currency bonds. Because these liabilities were denominated in their own currency, they did not rise in value when the currency fell.
That has freed policymakers to cut interest rates when the economy slows. Indonesia’s central bank, for example, slashed rates by three percentage points from December 2008 to August 2009. It cut rates by another point from October 2011 to February 2012. Thanks in part to its responsive central bank, Indonesia’s year-on-year growth rates over the past 20 quarters have been the most stable in the world.
Wise monetary policy was also one of the reasons cited for the Great Moderation enjoyed by the G7 economies. Another was the supposed depth and sophistication of the rich world’s financial systems, which, it was said, allowed households to smooth their spending, firms to diversify their borrowing and banks to unburden their balance-sheets. Both of these pillars of stability proved false comforts. Economists had not quite settled on an explanation for the Great Moderation before it inconveniently ceased to exist.
Worryingly, Asia’s great moderation has also been accompanied by sharply rising credit. According to Fred Neumann of HSBC, leverage is now higher than at any time since the Asian financial crisis. This credit expansion may represent healthy "financial deepening", which many economists believe is a cause of growth and stability. But rising leverage can also be a threat to stability. The late Hyman Minsky, among others, argued that drops in volatility allow firms and households to borrow more of the money they invest. Stability, in Minsky’s formulation, eventually becomes destabilising. Overleverage does not require excessive optimism, merely excessive certitude; not fast growth, merely steady growth.
Fortunately, Asia’s policymakers never shared the West’s faith in self-correcting financial systems. The region has pioneered "macro-prudential" regulations, designed to curb excessive credit and capital flows even without raising interest rates. In March, for example, Indonesia tightened loan-to-value ratios on mortgages and imposed minimum downpayments on car and motorbike loans.
Mr. Neumann is, however, skeptical that regulatory tightening can substitute for the monetary kind. Macro-prudential controls are not watertight, he notes. As long as capital remains cheap, money will leak. If the regulator lowers mortgage loan-to-value ratios, for example, banks may simply raise the appraised value of a home. If regulators impede foreign purchases of property, as Hong Kong just did, foreigners will seek inventive ways around the rules.
Hong Kong’s freedom to raise rates is constrained by its currency’s fixed link to the dollar, one of the few pegs to survive the Asian financial crisis. Other central banks do not have that excuse. Currency flexibility has given them the freedom to cut rates when growth slows. It should also allow them to raise rates when financial excess threatens—even if rates remain near zero in America, Europe and Japan. If stable growth allows lenders or borrowers to become overstretched, it can "sow the seeds of its own destruction", Mr. Neumann argues. Nothing great about that.
All of the following facts can support Mr. Neumann’s view of "macro-prudential controls are not watertight" EXCEPT that in Asia,________.
选项
A、banks are capable of offsetting the effect of lower loan-to-value ratios
B、the exchange rates of Asia’s economies are limited by currency pegs
C、foreign investors can bypass the rules to buy real estate
D、stable economic growth may lead to excess credit
答案
B
解析
细节题。根据题干定位到文章最后两段。最后一段第一句指出港币汇率的浮动受制于联系汇率制,而非亚洲所有国家和地区,所以正确答案为[B]。第十一段第四句提到监管机构降低抵押贷款价值比率,银行就会提高房产的评估价值以规避监管,故排除[A];第十一段最后一句提到如果监管机构阻挠外国人购置本国房产,外资就会另辟蹊径绕过资本监管,故排除[C];最后一段倒数第二句指出稳定的经济增长可能会导致过度借贷,从而引发严重的后果,故排除[D]。
转载请注明原文地址:https://kaotiyun.com/show/KVzK777K
0
专业英语八级
相关试题推荐
OnaLosAngelesstreetcornerin2000,Iwasthe"insideman"inaclassiccongamecalledthepigeondrop.AmagiciannamedDa
AccordingtoAlan’scoverstory,whatisthedifferenttraitbetweenabossandmostpeople?
SomePremisesunderWhichLinguistsOperateWhenwedolinguisticresearch,weneedtoknowsomeofthepremisesunderwhic
InawindowlessroomontheUniversityofCalifornia,Berkeley,campus,twoundergradsareplayingaMonopolygamethatoneoft
WhichofthefollowingstatementsisINCORRECTaccordingtothenewsitem?
InterculturalLearningManyteachersmaywonder"whatIamactuallydoing"sometimes.Itdoesn’tseemenoughtoteachgramma
Onceasourceof【B1】______businessactivity,Japan’skaraokeindustryhassloweddown.Japanesehavelesstosingaboutamid【B2
Inthego-goyearsofthelate1990s,noeconomictheoristlookedbetterthanJosephSchumpeter,theAustrianchampionofcapita
LakeTrummeninsouthernSwedenusedtobeapolluted,weed-chokedmess.Now,aftera$14millioncleanup,batherscrowditscle
NotsinceHarryTrumanseizedAmerica’ssteelmillsin1952ratherthanallowastriketoimperiltheconductoftheKoreanWar
随机试题
Itisn’toftenthatanentireindustryissymbolizedinthefigureofasinglehumanbeing,andsuchisthecasewithCanadiana
血虚头痛的临床特征是
产后出血的主要原因是
对于超过举证时限而提交的证据,人民法院应如何处理?()。
《刑法》第246条规定:“以暴力或者其他方法公然侮辱他人或者捏造事实诽谤他人,情节严重的,处三年以下有期徒刑、拘役、管制或者剥夺政治权利。”关于本条的理解,下列哪些选项是正确的?(卷二真题试卷第51题)
企业为生产产品而购进材料时需要向供货方支付增值税额,是进项税额,可计入所购材料成本。()
与新手相比,专家()。
国家文物局日前首次行使国家优先购买权,优先购回在嘉德春拍中以554.4万元成交的“陈独秀等致胡适信札”.此举将对国有博物馆和研究机构行使其优先购买权起到作用。但国家优先购买权并不适用于流失海外的圆明园兽首等被掠夺文物。最适合做这段文字标题的是:
列举二战期间中国政府参加的重要国际会议,并论述这些会议对中国的影响
Whatdoesthecompanywanttodo?
最新回复
(
0
)