首页
外语
计算机
考研
公务员
职业资格
财经
工程
司法
医学
专升本
自考
实用职业技能
登录
外语
Rich North, Hungry South A few years ago, the rich world’s worry about economic interaction with developing countries was th
Rich North, Hungry South A few years ago, the rich world’s worry about economic interaction with developing countries was th
admin
2010-04-30
36
问题
Rich North, Hungry South
A few years ago, the rich world’s worry about economic interaction with developing countries was that the poor could not profit from it. So unbalanced were terms of exchange between the North’s mighty industries and the South’s weakling sweatshops that trade between the two could be nothing more than exploitation of the one by the other: far from helping the poor countries, global integration would actually deepen their poverty. This fear has now given way to a pessimism that is equal and opposite—namely, that trade with the developing world will impoverish today’s rich countries.
Like the previous scare, this view contains an iota of truth—enough to lend plausibility. Also like its processor, it is a hysterical exaggeration. However, this new fear is more dangerous than the old one. The earlier scare tacitly affirmed that the industrial countries would suffer if they cut their links with the third world. Starting from there, campaigning in the North to restrict trade with developing countries was going to be an uphill straggle. Those who oppose deeper economic integration now have a better platform. Vital interests oblige the rich countries to protect their industries from the new onslaught. Unlike its processor, this idea may sell.
The grip that this thinking already has on popular opinion owes little to economic history or principles. The new fear, like the old one, express the conviction that growth in one part of the world must somehow come at the expense of another. This is a deeply rooted prejudice, and plainly wrong. Very nearly all of the world is more prosperous now than it was 30 years ago. Growth has been a story of mutual advance, not redistribution; and where living standards have not improved in recent decades (notably, in parts of Africa), excessive integration in the international economy has not been the cause.
Lending useful support to this first error is a second—the idea that there is only so much work to go round. If new technologies render some jobs obsolete, or if an increase in the supply of cheap imports makes other jobs uneconomic, the result must be a permanent rise in unemployment. Again, on a moment’s reflection, this is wrong: otherwise, technological progress this century would have pushed unemployment rates in the industrial countries to something in excess of 95%.
At the core of both fallacies is blindness to the adaptive power of a market economy. When today’s rich economies were predominantly agricultural, it seemed certain that rapidly rising farm productivity (thanks to new technology) would create a permanent army of unemployed. In the days of labor-intensive manufacturing, the same fears were expressed about labor-saving technology in the factory. Farm employment in the industrial countries has dwindled to nearly nothing: manufacturing employment in America now stands at a mere 15% of the labor-force. But other jobs have taken their place. As a result, these changes have happened alongside—indeed, they have been part and parcel of—an extraordinarily rapid, persistent and widely shared improvement in living standards.
Yet it does not suffice to refute elementary fallacies. Sophisticated alarmists avoid them (taking care, obviously, not to educate their listeners). But carefully, their case goes as follows. The breadth and intensity of third-world competition is increasing. The pressure is concentrated on particular parts of the economy—for the moment, on low-skill manufacturing. Wages there are being forced down and jobs lost. This change will accelerate. Modem societies (with weak ties of family and religion) are no longer equipped to withstand such strains. The result will be great social distress.
This argument rests on a series of claims that need to be examined one by one. One survey does this at length. It agrees that in many industries the developing countries are offering much stiffer competition than before, and that this will continue. It also agrees that the wages and jobs of low-skilled workers are under pressure as a result. But it argues, first, that these effects have been overdone. Third-world incomes are automatically regulated by international differences in productivity; the faster their advantage in cheap labor will be eroded. Moreover, that advantage has itself been exaggerated. Labor costs are only a small part of total costs, especially in manufacturing; in other respects—in complementary physical and human capital—the poor countries will remain at a big disadvantage for years.
So the pressures have been overstated. On the other hand, what the industrial countries stand to gain from faster growth in the third world has been altogether ignored. Stronger competition will push rich-country producers to invest more and improve their efficiency; expanding markets for rich-country exports will allow them to reap new economies of scale. Even more important is the direct effect that greater productivity in the third world will have on the North’s standard of living. Cheaper imports mean lower prices and, hence, higher real incomes. The potential gain is large.
In the aggregate, the economic benefits to the North from faster growth in the third world seem certain to outweigh the costs. Remember the gains to the world’s poor countries and the global benefits are immense. And yet, you might ask, What consolation is this to the rich countries’ losers? Perhaps the social costs for the North are so great that the economic gain should be refused.
Suppose this is right, it would follow that new technology ought to be resisted with even greater urgency than imports from the third world. Technological progress, after all, is an even more powerful engine of economic change. It asks the citizens of rich countries to strike the same bargain they are offered by faster growth in the developing world: in the aggregate, it benefits them, but there are losers along the way. Ross Perot and the other leading alarmists on third world growth have not yet argued for prohibitive taxes on all forms of labor-saving innovation. This can only be an oversight. Innovation remains the greater threat social harmony—and believing this requires no imagination. Machines have been destroying jobs, wrecking communities and spreading misery for centuries.
Doubtless, some argue seriously for a punitive innovation tax. Most people would regard the idea as absurd. Why? Not because new technology brings nothing but good (the social costs are real) but
because, with time, the benefits overwhelm the costs. So it will prove with trade with the developing world.
As in accommodating the changes brought by new technology, however, governments have an important job—to protect the losers without denying the benefits to citizens at large. This is a crucial point: if the case against trade with the third world gains ground, it will be partly because governments fail in that challenge. It will not do to provide a welfare system that pays a subsistence income to those whose jobs disappear, for boredom and idleness, even at a bearable standard of living, are socially corrosive. Far more needs to be done to help workers acquire the skills they need to switch jobs—and, in many cases, to equip them with the literacy and numeracy that they may well have lacked in the first place. Steadily expanding programs of adults’ education, better job-placement services, grants and other help for those who need to move house to find work, and explicit subsidies for some kinds of low-wage employment would all be sensible ways to spend part of the dividend that growth in the South will pay to the North.
This is an agenda that governments have been too slow to develop. Unless they start to act soon, the alarmists may win more converts. And the marvelous opportunity that is now before the world may be jeopardized. To build obstacles on the developing countries’ path out of poverty would be the crime of the century. Happily, it is preventable.
The survey argues that third-world incomes are automatically regulated by______.
选项
答案
international differences in productivity
解析
本题的关键词是The survey,寻读到第7段可知几乎整段都是针对the survey而言,因此能最终确定答案:international differences in productivity。
转载请注明原文地址:https://kaotiyun.com/show/PAOK777K
0
大学英语六级
相关试题推荐
Theinstinctivefoundationoftheintellectuallifeiscuriosity,whichisfoundamonganimalsinitselementaryform.Intellige
A、Theyarelookingforanapartmenttolivein.B、Theyarediscussinglivingplacesandchildren’seducation.C、Theyarecomplai
A、Thewomangivesthevehicleup.B、Thewomanwillbuythevehicle.C、Thewomanasksforalowerprice.D、Thewomanwilltalkto
A、Theweekendhasdecreasedinlength.B、Thenumberofnationalholidayshasincreased.C、Peopleworkfewerdaysperweek.D、Peo
Advertiserscanuse(36)______media,ormeans,todelivertheirsalesmessages.The(37)______mediaarenewspapers,magazines,
Thewriterdocsnotbelievethat______.Thelionrepresentsthosewhoare______.
A、At5:30.B、At6:00.C、Before6:00.D、After6:00.DAccordingtotheman,whenisitcheapertomakeaphonecall?
Mostpeoplewouldbe【S1】bythehighqualityofmedicine【S2】tomostAmericans.Thereisalotofspecialization,agreatdeal
A、Venusistoohot.B、Thereisnowaterthere.C、Thereisnooil.D、Itislackingincarbondioxide.A该题问“根据卡尔教授的说法,金星的大气存在什么问题?
A、Theyarebecominginsane.B、Theyfeelratherbad-tempered.C、Theybecomeviolentlyaggressive.D、Theyaresufferingtoothache.
随机试题
狭义的市场、广义的市场各有何含义?
波长λ=5000A的单色光垂直照射到宽度a=0.25mm的单缝上,单缝后面放置一凸透镜,在凸透镜的焦平面上放置一屏幕,用以观测衍射条纹。今测得屏幕上中央明条纹一侧第三个暗条纹和另一侧第三个暗条纹之间的距离为d=12mm,则凸透镜的焦距f为()。
[背景资料]某小区内拟建一座6层普通砖混结构住宅楼,外墙厚370mm,内墙厚240mm,抗震设防烈度7度,某施工单位于2009年5月与建设单位签订了该工程总承包合同。合同工程量清单报价中写明:瓷砖墙面积为1000m2,综合单价为110元/m2。事件一:
英译汉:“Food--borne Virus”,正确的翻译为( )。
甲房地产开发企业将自行开发楼盘的90%对外出售,10%对外出租,另将10年前购入的一所办公用房转让,则下列关于印花税扣除的规定符合税法要求的是()。
根据《担保法》,当事人对保证方式没有约定或者约定不明确的()
1,4,2,16,12,()。
宾夕法尼亚大学的认知心理学研究小组发现.当一方球员由右至左向对方球员实行铲断时,对于那些来自阅读习惯为由左至右的国家的裁判来说,判定犯规的概率要比铲断是由左至右时高出5%。这种对有异于惯常视觉体验的行为“看不顺眼”的心理偏好此前已经被电影导演和漫画家们发现
巡回画派
已知:数组:int[]al={2,3,5,7,11,13}int[]a2={1001,1002,1003,1004,1005,1006,1007}在语句System.arraycopy(a1,2,a2,3,4)执行后,数组int
最新回复
(
0
)