首页
外语
计算机
考研
公务员
职业资格
财经
工程
司法
医学
专升本
自考
实用职业技能
登录
外语
Towards the end of Thinking, Fast and Slow, Daniel Kahneman laments that he and his late collaborator, Amos Tversky, are often c
Towards the end of Thinking, Fast and Slow, Daniel Kahneman laments that he and his late collaborator, Amos Tversky, are often c
admin
2013-08-05
47
问题
Towards the end of Thinking, Fast and Slow, Daniel Kahneman laments that he and his late collaborator, Amos Tversky, are often credited with showing that humans make "irrational" choices. That term is too strong, he says, to describe the variety of mental mishaps to which people systematically fall prey. Readers of his book may disagree. Mr. Kahneman, an Israeli-American psychologist and Nobel economics laureate, has delivered a full catalogue of the biases, shortcuts and cognitive illusions to which our species regularly succumbs. In doing so he makes it plain that Homo economicus the rational model of human behaviour beloved of economists—is as fantastical as a unicorn.
In one experiment described by Mr. Kahneman, participants asked to imagine that they have been given £50 behave differently depending on whether they are then told they can "keep" £20 or must "lose" £30--though the outcomes are identical. He also shows that it is more threatening to say that a disease kills "1,286 in every 10,000 people", than to say it kills "24. 14% of the population", even though the second mention is twice as deadly. Vivid language often overrides basic arithmetic.
Some findings are downright peculiar. Experimental subjects who have been "primed" to think of money, perhaps by seeing a picture of dollar bills, will act more selfishly. So if someone nearby drops some pencils, these subjects will pick up fewer than their non-primed counterparts. Even obliquely suggesting the concept of old age will inspire people to walk more slowly—though feeling elderly never crossed their mind, they will later report.
After all this the human brain looks less like a model of rationality and more like a giddy teenager; flighty, easily distracted and lacking in self-awareness. Yet this book is not a counsel of despair. Its awkward title refers to Mr. Kahneman’s two-tier model of cognition: "System 1" is quick, intuitive and responsible for the quirks and mistakes described above(and many others). "System 2", by contrast, is slow, deliberative and less prone to error. System 2 kicks in when we are faced with particularly complex problems, but much of the time it is all too happy to let the impulsive System 1 get its way.
What, then, is System 1 good for? Rather a lot, it turns out. In a world that often demands swift judgment and rapid decision-making, a creature who solely relied on deliberative thinking wouldn’t last long. Moreover, System 1 generally works well. As Mr. Kahneman says, "most of our judgments and actions are appropriate most of the time". He urges readers to counteract what he considers to be mistakes of System 1 thinking, such as the "loss aversion" that deters people from accepting favourable gambles(such as a 50-50 chance to win $200 or lose $100). He also recommends checking the performance of an investment portfolio no more than once a quarter, to limit needless anguish over short-term fluctuations and the "useless churning" of shares.
Mr. Kahneman does not dwell on the possible evolutionary origins of our cognitive biases, nor does he devote much time to considering why some people seem naturally better at avoiding error than others.
Still this book, his first for a non-specialist audience, is a profound one. As Copernicus removed the Earth from the centre of the universe and Darwin knocked humans off their biological perch, Mr. Kahneman has shown that we are not the paragons of reason we assume ourselves to be. Often hailed as the father of behavioural economics(with Tversky as co-parent), his work has influenced a range of disciplines and has even inspired some policy.
But the true consequences of his findings are only starting to emerge. When he presents the poor victims of his experiments with conclusive proof of their errors, the typical reaction is not a chastened pledge to shape up, but confused silence, followed by business as usual. No one likes to be told he is wrong.
According to the passage, the human brain can be described as
选项
A、irrational.
B、oblivious.
C、disorderly.
D、capricious.
答案
D
解析
细节题。由the human brain定位至第四段首句。句中flighty意为“反复无常的”,与capricious“善变的,反复无常的”含义相同,故[D]为答案。虽然句中提到less like a model of rationality,但并没有完全否认其理性的一面,排除[A];句中的easily distracted意为“容易分心的”,而oblivious意为“健忘的”,与原文不符,排除[B];另外一个提及的特点是lacking in self-awareness,即“缺少自觉意识”,并非[C]项“混乱的,凌乱的”,排除该项。
转载请注明原文地址:https://kaotiyun.com/show/Wa4O777K
0
专业英语八级
相关试题推荐
Whichofthefollowingworksexpressedthedesireforanescapefromsocietyandareturntonature?
WhatIsAnAmerican?"Ican’tmakeyouout,"HerryJameshasMrs.TristramsaytotheAmerican,"whetheryouareverysimpl
Thefarmers’federationshavesaidthatthestrikewilllastfor
______proposedTGgrammar.
Thejob-seekingperspectiveisparticularlygoodforthefollowingmajorsEXCEPT______.
WhatwerethethingsinBritainthatDr.Mathewfoundmoststrangewhenhefirstarrived?
Researchersinvestigatingbrainsizeandmentalabilitysaytheirworkoffersevidencethateducationprotectsthemindfromthe
Accordingtotheinterviewer,whatattitudedomostyoungpeopleholdtowardskeepinghealthy?
ThomasMalthuspublishedhis"EssayonthePrincipleofPopulation"almost200yearsago.Eversincethen,forecastershavebei
Theworldisgoingthroughthebiggestwaveofmergersandacquisitionseverwitnessed.TheprocesssweepsfromhyperactiveAme
随机试题
肺源性心脏病导致心力衰竭的最主要原因是
燕麦细胞支气管肺癌,不同部位的类癌燕麦细胞癌
审慎不包括
监理单位应当依照法律、法规以及()对节能工程建设实施监理。
下列费用中,应计入建筑安装工程施工机具使用费的有()。
投资者预期股票价格上涨,可以通过(),构造牛市价差期权。Ⅰ.购买较低执行价格的看跌期权和出售较高执行价格的看跌期权Ⅱ.购买较高执行价格的看跌期权和出售较低执行价格的看跌期权Ⅲ.购买较低执行价格的看涨期权和出售较高执行价格的看涨期权
在一般情况下,应付账款不需要函证,主要是因为注册会计师能够取得购货发票等外部凭证来证实应付账款的余额。()
导游讲解中的“突出重点法”要求导游员在讲解时突}}{()。
招用未满16周岁的未成年人从事危险作业的,由()部门责令改正,处以罚款。
Readthefollowingtextanddecidewhichanswerbestfitseachspace.Forquestions26-45,markoneletterA,B,CorDony
最新回复
(
0
)