首页
外语
计算机
考研
公务员
职业资格
财经
工程
司法
医学
专升本
自考
实用职业技能
登录
外语
A newspaper cannot publish for 174 years without some mistakes. This one has made its share. We thought Britain was safe in the
A newspaper cannot publish for 174 years without some mistakes. This one has made its share. We thought Britain was safe in the
admin
2018-01-01
50
问题
A newspaper cannot publish for 174 years without some mistakes. This one has made its share. We thought Britain was safe in the European exchange-rate mechanism just weeks before it crashed out; we noted in 1999 that $10 oil might reach $5; and in 2003 we supported the invasion of Iraq. For individuals, like publications, errors are painful—particularly now, when the digital evidence of failure is both accessible and indelible. But they are also inevitable. The trick is to err well: to recognise mistakes and learn from them. Worryingly, humanity may be getting worse at owning up to its goofs.
Few enjoy the feeling of being caught out in an error. But real trouble starts when the desire to avoid a reckoning leads to a refusal to grapple with contrary evidence. Economists often assume that people are rational. Yet years of economic research illuminate the ways in which human cognition veers from rationality. Studies confirm that people frequently disregard information that conflicts with their view of the world. Why should that be? Last year Roland Benabou and Jean Tirole presented a framework for thinking about the problem. In many ways, beliefs are like other goods. People spend time and resources building them, and derive value from them. Some beliefs are like consumption goods. Other beliefs provide value by shaping behaviour. The conviction that one is a good salesman may help generate the confidence needed to close sales.
Because beliefs are not simply tools for making good decisions, but are treasured in their own right, new information that challenges them is unwelcome. People often engage in "motivated reasoning" to manage such challenges. Mr. Benabou classifies this into three categories. "Strategic ignorance" is when a believer avoids information offering conflicting evidence. In "reality denial" troubling evidence is rationalised away: houseprice bulls might conjure up fanciful theories for why prices should behave unusually, and supporters of a disgraced politician might invent conspiracies. And lastly, in "self-signalling", the believer creates his own tools to interpret the facts in the way he wants; an unhealthy person might decide that going for a daily run proves he is well.
Motivated reasoning is a cognitive bias to which better-educated people are especially prone. Not all the errors it leads to are costly. But when biases are shared, danger lurks. Motivated reasoning helps explain why viewpoints polarise even as more information is more easily available than ever before. That it is easy to find convincing demolitions of climate-change myths, for example, has not curbed misinformation on the topic. But the demand for good (or bad) information is uneven. Polling shows, for example, that Democrats with high levels of scientific knowledge are more concerned about climate change than fellow partisans with less scientific background. Even, or especially, sophisticated news consumers look for what they want to find.
Work by Mr. Benabou suggests that groupthink is highest when people within groups face a shared fate: when choosing to break from a group is unlikely to spare an individual the costs of the group’s errors. If a politician’s fortunes rise and fall with his party’s, breaking from groupthink brings little individual benefit (but may impose costs). The incentive to engage in motivated reasoning is high as a result. Even as the facts on a particular issue converge in one direction, parties can still become polarised around belief-sets. That, in turn, can make it harder for a party member to derive any benefit from breaking ranks. Indeed, the group has an incentive to delegitimise independent voices. So the unanimity of views can be hard to escape until it contributes to a crisis.
Lowering the cost of admitting error could help defuse these crises. A new issue of Econ Journal Watch, an online journal, includes a symposium in which prominent economic thinkers are asked to provide their "most regretted statements". Held regularly, such exercises might take the shame out of changing your mind. Yet the symposium also shows how hard it is for scholars to grapple with intellectual regret. Some contributions are candid; Tyler Cowen’s analysis of how and why he underestimated the risk of financial crisis in 2007 is enlightening. But some disappoint, picking out regrets that cast the writer in a flattering light or using the opportunity to shift blame.
Public statements of regret are risky in a rigidly polarised world. Admissions of error both provide propaganda for ideological opponents and annoy fellow-travellers. Some economists used to seethe when members of the guild acknowledged that trade liberalisation could yield costs as well as benefits. In the long run, such self-censorship probably eroded trust in economists’ arguments more than it built support for trade. It is rarely in the interest of those in the right to pretend that they are never wrong.
Why should the scholars admit the errors they have committed? What are the possible risks of admitting one’s errors?
选项
答案
only when we recognise mistakes / it is possible to learn lessons from the errors / but the cost of admitting error could be high / in a rigidly polarised world, public expression of regret could be risky / for ideological opponents, the admissions of one’s error could provide evidence of propaganda / "annoy fellow-travellers" / in economists’ argument, the admission of one’s error ("self-censorship") might destroy + reduce trust / instead of building support
解析
转载请注明原文地址:https://kaotiyun.com/show/qqSO777K
本试题收录于:
NAETI高级口译笔试题库外语翻译证书(NAETI)分类
0
NAETI高级口译笔试
外语翻译证书(NAETI)
相关试题推荐
首先,我感谢莱文校长的邀请,使我有机会来到世界著名学府耶鲁大学,同青年朋友和老师们相聚在一起。进入耶鲁大学的校园,看到莘莘学子青春洋溢的脸庞,呼吸着书香浓郁的空气,我不由回想起40年前在北京清华大学的求学岁月。当年老师们对我的教诲,同学们给我的启发,我至今
世界著名的《格萨尔王传》是藏族人民在漫长历史长河中创造出来的一部珍贵的长篇英雄史诗,是中国乃至世界文学宝库中少有的珍品,但一直是通过民间说唱艺人口头流传为了保护藏民族的这一文化瑰宝,西藏自治区于1979年成立了抢救、整理《格萨尔王传》的专门机构,进行全面搜
A、Helikedtoattendbeautycontests.B、Hewouldkeeponbuyingandsellinghotstocks.C、Heoftenboughtinstocksoflesserco
A、precautiousB、skepticalC、approvingD、indifferentA正确识别某些重要表达后面蕴涵的意义。
JohnCiardigothismaster’sdegreefromtheUniversityofMichiganin1939andhaspublishedmorethan40poems.
Peopleofdifferentfieldscametogetherforthesamedreamofbuildingasmartcity.
Peopleofdifferentfieldscametogetherforthesamedreamofbuildingasmartcity.
自父母离异后,我从一个娇生惯养的孩子,转变成了一个通情达理的大学生。父母离异前,我指望着母亲服侍我。她为我洗衣、做饭、洗碗,甚至为我铺床。我15岁时父亲离开了我们,之后一切都变了。母亲找了份全职工作供养我们,我成了家里有时间做家务的人。另外,我在周末兼职挣
Ifyoufindyouspendmorethanyoumake,thereareonlytwothingstodo:decreaseyourspendingor【C1】______.It’softeneasie
Itshouldnotbetakenforgrantedthatrecyclingismoreefficientthanchuckingsomethingaway.Comparingallthecosts,inclu
随机试题
Aliceisthetallestof______intheSmithfamily.
下列除哪项外。均是厥证的病因
按照金属切割过程中加热方法的不同大致可以把切割方法分为( )。
新发生不良贷款的外部原因包括()
20世纪70年代中叶,K公司垄断了美国90%的胶卷市场以及85%的相机市场份额。2000年之后,数码照相技术开始发展,此后的数年间,数码相机迅速地被人们接受。但是和传统的胶卷产业相比,数码照相产业技术粗糙、产值微薄、利润率低、远景不明。对数码技术短暂的尝试
下列增值税适用税率的说法错误的是()。
《孙子兵法》曰:“水因地而制流,兵因敌而制胜。故兵无常势,水无常形。能因敌而胜者,谓之神。”从哲学的观点看。这段话表明()。
琵琶:木材:乐器
根据继承人继承遗产的方式,可以将继承分为()。
Therearetwocommontypesinpagereplacementalgorithm:stackandnon-stackstrategies.Whenarealpagenumberincreaseonly
最新回复
(
0
)